energy subsidies

Part 2 of my review of energy subsidies and the Romney campaign is a bit long for a blog posting.  Thus, it has been uploaded as a PDF instead, and can be accessed here.  Issues covered include conflicts between the private equity world view and good national policy; how appropriate adjustments to Romney's subsidy baseline alter the conclusions he drew from the figures, and a discussion of missing subsidies in a number of key areas:  tax-exempt oil and gas master limited partnerships, inadequate fuel taxes to pay for highways, huge losses on federal resource sales, and the funding of energy security.

My first posting on Romney's energy subsidy policy focused on data errors in his tabulation of subsidies to green energy.

Table 2: Subsidy Definitions Vary by Country, Lead to Gaps in Reporting and Reform Commitments

Table summarizing the ways G20 member countries have defined reportable subsidies to fossil fuels, and the gaps these definitions open up to missing entire classes of government support to the fossil fuels sector.  The table has been extracted from Phasing Out Fossil-Fuel Subsidies in the G20:  A Progress Update.  

Green Scissors 2012: Cutting Wasteful and Environmentally Harmful Spending

This report is the latest of a string of assessments produced over the past 18 years to identify and quantify federal subsidies that harm the environment as well as waste prodigious amounts of money.  The exact coalition producing the reports varies a bit year-to-year, but the Green Scissors Campaign has always been a collaboration between budget and environmental groups aimed at eliminating wasteful spending that is harmful to the environment.

Natural gas fracking well in Louisiana

I am often asked what forms of energy should be subsidized. Though much of my work documents how subsidies end up wasting money and don't achieve their stated goals, I don't universally reject the use of public resources to help implement important societal shifts. Clearly, we have a moral responsibility to use both public (and private) money to alleviate suffering in our country -- whether due to a lack of food, heat, or illness. The case for subsidizing systematic changes in our economy (such as to a lower carbon footprint) could be made as well, though not in the way it is usually argued in policy circles. 

Once one starts moving from the theoretical use of subsidies to actual policies that transfer large amounts of wealth, trouble begins.  Implementing a transfer policy that is efficient and effective in achieving the desired structural shifts is not easy.  Often, subsidies are put forth as a solution to problems that could actually be better addressed through desubsidization of competing goods or services. In many other cases, subsidy policy is gamed to the benefit of entrenched interests, and the policies can slow rather than accelerate the desired shifts.

Power LinesThus, I do not have a list of "most deserving" subsidy recipients.  Unlike Congress, I do not believe that I can reliably predict the most effective energy paths for the country.  Finding a cool new energy technology is one thing.  However, identifying the set of options that are actually going to work technically, that are economic to implement, that can gain market share quickly enough to make a difference, and that can be scaled to the magnitude needed without creating large ancillary problems is a different task altogether (see "Energy Transition: Mapping an Appropriate Role for Government").

Thus, I focus instead on getting the policy structure correct so that the best choices are more likely to win out in the marketplace.  This approach channels the dynamism and discipline of market forces, while allowing multiple pathways to be pursued at once.  Since there is attrition at every stage of new innovation, scale-up, and market adaption, having multiple pathways at the start is necessary if there are to be sufficient successes by the end.

For identifying how to allocate public support, something as simple as defining the real end-goal of the subsidies is a critical starting point, but can be surprisingly difficult to nail down.  Is it energy independence (proponents argue we should subsidize anything made in the US or tax oil imports)?  Counter-acting climate change (proponents argue for subsidizing lower-carbon fuels)?  Poverty reduction (where perhaps subsidies focus on fuels used by the poor)?

Political forces pass legislation by pooling together interest groups. In the subsidy arena, this means a "big-tent" process where everybody important (i.e., their support is needed to pass the bill) gets something.  The more powerful groups get more. The "real" objective of the policy often becomes secondary to shifing around piles of cash.

So here's my guidelines on policy pre-requisites if a subsidy program is to have any chance of success:

  • Do no harm. If you are trying to solve a problem, the first step should be to remove subsidies to behaviors that exacerbate it. Thus, if we don’t like high oil imports but still have reduced taxes on foreign subsidiaries, socialize the costs of oil stockpiling, and don't recover the costs of oil security from users -- policies that all make imported oil cheaper -- we ought to fix it.  Similarly, if we care about climate change, stop subsidizing ghg-intensive activities. Ending subsidies to coal mining is an obvious step, but there are many others.  Tax-exempt bonds for pollution control equipment on power plants (clean air is important, but coal has been a main beneficiary of the bonds and should be paying full price for the controls); landfill gas recovery (a favorite of EPA – but fugitive emissions remain high, the control costs should be internalized in tip fees, and the subsidies undermine climate friendlier reuse and recycling); and all sorts of land conversion and cropping patterns that drive up emissions.

  • Focus on outcomes, not inputs. If you decide offer subsidies, subsidize the outcome, not a Congressionally pre-defined pathway to that outcome. Otherwise, you get balkanized policies -- such as different rules for each possible approach to alternative-fueled vehicles; or that focus on lower carbon electricity when there are many cheaper ghg-reduction strategies that have nothing to do with power generation.  Interestingly, federal energy subsidies are nearly always directed towards the supply side.  Demand-side options to curb energy or raw materials use can be less expensive and faster to deploy, but are far too often ignored. This is a costly error. In fact, the outcome needs to be defined carefully to be neutral in its impact. Rather than “reduce gasoline use in the United States” it needs to be something like “reduce energy consumed per passenger-mile or vehicle-mile traveled." That way, you have all drive technologies competing against each other, while also opening the playing field to innovative ways to reduce the ghg-intensity of transport -- boosting load factors or shifting transport modes, for example. With something like energy for the poor, there is probably no way around some subsidies to fuel consumption. However, weighting total spending too heavily on supplying fuel to old and leaky homes – rather than financing insulation – is also self-defeating.  Addressing structural problems (for example, split incentives on energy-efficient capital upgrades for landlords and tenants that result in sub-optimal conservation investments in rental housing) can also be more important over the long-term.

  • Pool resources linked to outcomes; force alternative pathways to compete for funds on offer. Once you’ve defined the objective carefully, the next step is to put a single subsidy budget linked to that objective and to open it to competitive tender. Thus, rather than ten separate subsidies to alternative fuels (each carefully crafted by lobbyists to guarantee public money to their clients), you have a larger pool of money that both entices more activity and forces the alternative ways to meet the target objective to bid against each other. The lowest subsidy increment per objective delivered (e.g., per mt CO2e reduced) would win. This type of approach is at the core of many renewable portfolio standards.  However, in addition to restricting ghg reductions to just the power sector, the RPS' are often layered on top of all sorts of other subsidies, distorting the reasons particular resources are able to submit winning supply bids.

  • Even the good solutions have drawbacks; don't ignore them. Resist the temptation to cut deals for power sources you “just know” are the right path. For example, all of them should have to go through environmental permitting (MN exempted ethanol facilities some years back). All of them should have to pay for the water they use (virtually no thermal power plant in the country pays for cooling water, even though the sector uses as much as agriculture). All of them should have to have appropriate bonding or post-closure funds if they are leaving big changes to the landscape that will need to be dealt with by taxpayers should the firm go belly up. If these rules are applied evenly, they shouldn’t disadvantage the newer energy technologies. They may, however, force manufacturers to deal more carefully with problems ahead of time -- for example, large concrete pads at remote windmill sites; heavy metals in PV panel production; or massive land conversion for biofuels. Problems do arise if high standards are being set for emerging energy resources while conventional fuels have been exempted from dealing with many of these types of problems for decades (e.g., drilling wastes from oil wells or socializing many of the costs of nuclear waste management). The solution needs to be bringing conventional fuels into appropriate controls rather than exempting emerging fuels from them as well.

Here’s a graphical example of what happens all too often when subsidies are politicized.

 

Cost of Subsidizing Fossil Fuels Is High, but Cutting Them Is Tough

...Moreover, citizens and companies that rely on fossil fuels usually do not pay the full cost of resulting environmental  problems like oil spills, sludge from coal mines and greenhouse gases, and for health problems from polluted air.

Estimates of the cost of these effects — or “externalities” in the ungainly jargon of economists — vary.

Burning Public Money for Dirty Energy: Misdirected Subsidies for “Waste-to-Energy” Incinerators

Burning Public Money for Dirty Energy presents an overview of how U.S. energy policies are creating a range of subsidies for municipal waste incineration (MSW) projects, including emerging waste burning technologies of gasification, pyrolysis and plasma arc incineration. This report also identifies incentives for a wider spectrum of industries that are starting to identify as “waste-to-energy” projects, such as landfill gas to energy systems and anaerobic digestion (or biogas) facilities.

Natural gas fracking well in Louisiana

Like implant dentists or utility accountants, subsidy wonks can go to trade meetings (yes, meetings on natural resource subsidies do exist) to find people who talk our language.  In that "safe" space, we can be met with a knowing nod as we wax poetic on the difference between revenue loss and outlay equivalents, or what is missing from a price gap estimate. 

Go into the normal world though, and not only does this talk make no sense, but it drives people out of the room fast -- really fast.  Sure, they care about the effects of massive subsidies to natural resource extraction: dwindling forests and aquifers, mountain top removal to tap into coal deposits, pollution, and degraded land.  But if you can't make the link between the policy and the impact, it is hard to leverage the political support needed to change the policies.

This is an issue that most of us subsidy wonks have grappled with over the years, unfortunately, I think, with limited success.  One person who has done this extremely well is Annie Leonard, who debuted with a very well received animated web documentary "The Story of Stuff" that explored the links between what we buy and the environmental damage caused by its production.

Today brings her newest release: the "The Story of Broke" which looks at how governments seem to find the money to give subsidies to powerful and often polluting industries, but then claim empty wallets when it is time to fund social programs.  In full disclosure, I provided a fair bit of input to them on subsidy types and impacts.  That said, I provide information on subsidies to a wide variety of people and organizations, from home-schooled high school debaters (their topic a few years back was on ethanol and ethanol subsidies) to reporters, educators and government staff.  I never know what will come from it. 

In this particular case, I am quite impressed with how "The Story of Broke," well, tells its story.  Annie and her team have captured some of the core issues I've struggled to convey, and they've done so in catchy and readily accessible ways: 

  • That subsidies aren't just about cash transfers, but often involve extremely valuable shifting of risks from private investors onto taxpayers;
  • That power matters a great deal (and more than merit) in who ends up with the biggest subsidy trough;
  • That all of these policies involve trade-offs, but beneficiary industries try to define trade-offs quite narrowly in an effort to argue that their subsidies are benefiting all of us, or that the costs of reform are too high;
  • And that patterns of support over a period of years or decades accumulate to produce dramatically different outcomes with respect to industrial structure and market options than what would have occurred without government subsidies or with a different pattern of support.

Here's hoping her ability to capture and convey this information so widely will help alleviate the bottlenecks to sensible policy reform.

Watch the video:

Natural gas fracking well in Louisiana

Last week, the New York Times ran an article ("Future of Solar and Wind Power May Hinge on Federal Aid" by Kate Galbraith) discussing the reliance of solar and wind energy on federal subsidies. Bernard L. Weinstein, associate director of the Maguire Energy Institute at Cox School of Business, Southern Methodist University, wrote a letter critiquing these subsidies, advocating instead a policy to push for more oil and gas exploration, arguing they would require "no new subsidies."  The Institute was funded by Cary Maguire of the Maguire Oil Company and prepares students for jobs in the field.

The Times requested responses to the letter for their Sunday Dialogue yesterday.  Mine was not selected, but covers some points not raised in the letters that were.  It is reprinted below.

To the Editor:

Bernard Weinstein has concluded that the “renewable power industry has become addicted to federal subsidies and probably can’t stand on its own without them.”  After more than twenty years of tracking subsidies to energy both in the US and abroad, allow me to suggest that the addicts’ ward is overflowing.  The nuclear industry has been pushing for massive government subsidies for decades, and won’t build a new facility without them.  Arguments that somehow other countries know how to “do it right” are more often based on an incomplete understanding of foreign subsidies than to some miracle economic model.    

New petrol refinery?  Coal plant with carbon capture and sequestration?  Big subsidies also rule.   Liquid biofuels producers (still mostly corn ethanol) are addicts too.  They are fighting hard to keep expiring subsidies alive even though the Renewable Fuel Standard (forcing us to buy their products at above-market prices) will quickly pick up the slack.

Weinstein’s figures are also inaccurate.  He focuses only on tax breaks, though it is total subsidies through all mechanisms that distort energy markets and investment patterns.  Missing are the critical, and often enormous, subsidies that flow to various fuels through loan guarantees, royalty exemptions, liability caps, nationalized supply security or waste management obligations, purchase mandates, and subsidized government-owned energy enterprises.  Even his tax break tally is picked from problematic data from the Energy Information Administration (EIA).  EIA’s numbers have consistently been at the far low-end of subsidy reviews.  They miss many tax breaks of great benefit to the energy sector; and ignore quite large variance in the tax subsidies they do include.  Incorporating tax subsidy estimates from both of the federal sources (Joint Committee on Taxation and Treasury) rather than just Treasury, for example, would have boosted EIA’s 2007 total subsidy estimates by a third, and the share to oil and gas by nearly 125 percent.

Expand beyond just fiscal subsidies and Weinstein’s academic framing of the simplistic “drill, baby, drill” argument totally dissolves.  A recent analysis by economists Nicholas Muller, Robert Mendelsohn, and William Nordhaus estimated that petroleum-fired electric power generation caused gross external damages five times the industry’s value added.  Coal-fired power had damages more than twice its value added.  A Harvard Medical School study in February pegged the external damages from coal well above $100 billion per year.  Shortfalls in federal highway funding, which is supposed to be paid through taxes on (the mostly petroleum) motor fuels, were $70 billion in 2007 according to analysis by Pew’s Subsidyscope project.  That number alone far exceeds total energy subsidies reported by EIA; and at $700 billion over ten years would cover more than half the initial deficit reduction target for the Super Committee.

Price signals do need to play a much bigger role in energy markets, including renewables, if we are move towards a cleaner energy future in an economically-efficient way.  However, Weinstein’s selective and inaccurate vision of market reform is unlikely to take us in the right direction.

Regards,

Doug Koplow
Earth Track, Inc.
Cambridge, MA 02140

 

What Would Jefferson Do? The Historical Role of Federal Subsidies in Shaping America’s Energy Future

Using data culled from the academic literature, government documents, and NGO sources, in this paper we examine the extent of federal support (as well as support from the various states in pre-Civil War America) for emerging energy technologies in their early days. We then analyze discrete periods in history when the federal government enacted specific subsidies.